PSYCH OpenIR  > 中国科学院行为科学重点实验室
基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策中为自己–为所有人决策差异的眼动研究
其他题名When expectation-maximization-based theories work or do not work: An eye-tracking study of the discrepancy between everyone and every one
刘洪志3; 李兴珊1,2; 李纾1,2,4; 饶俪琳1,2
第一作者刘洪志
通讯作者邮箱raoll@psych.ac.cn (饶俪琳)
摘要

主流的风险决策理论专家发展了一系列基于期望值最大化(expectation-maximization)的理论,以期捕获所有人的风险决策行为。然而大量证据表明,这些基于期望值最大化的理论并不能如同描述性理论那样理想地描述单一个体的决策行为。本研究采用眼动追踪技术,系统考察了个体在为所有人决策与为自己决策时的风险决策行为及信息加工过程的差异。本研究发现,基于期望值最大化的理论可捕获为所有人决策或为自己多次决策时的情况,却不能很好捕获个体为自己进行单次决策时的情况。本研究结果有助于理解基于期望值最大化的理论与启发式/非基于期望值最大化的理论的边界,为风险决策理论的划分和发展提供实证参考。

其他摘要

Mainstream theorists in risky decision-making have developed various expectation-maximization-based theories with the ambitious goal of capturing everyone’s choices. However, ample evidence has revealed that these theories could not capture every individual’s (“every one’s”) actual risky choice as descriptive theories. Substantial research has demonstrated that people do not follow the logical process suggested by expectation-maximization-based theories when making risky choices but rather rely on simplifying heuristics. From our perspective, the possible reason why mainstream decision theorists did not abandon the framework of expectation is that these theorists never doubted the validity of the expectation rule as a descriptive rule in describing decision-making under risk. We believe that expectation-maximization-based theories may capture risky choices when individuals make decisions for everyone. However, whether these theories could capture risky choices when individuals make decisions for themselves cannot be taken for granted. We thus used an eye-tracking technique to explore whether a theory for everyone would work well for every one. A total of 52 college students participated in the experiment. Three risky choice tasks were conducted in the present study: a D-everyone task, a D-multiple task, and a D-single task. In the D-everyone task, participants were asked to choose the more optimal option out of two options under the assumption that their selection would be the final decision for everyone who was facing the same choice—that is, everyone would be subject to the same choice but could receive different outcomes. In the D-multiple task, participants were asked to choose between the two options under the assumption that their selection would be applied a total of 100 times. In the D-single task, participants were asked to choose between the two options under the assumption that their selection would be applied only once to themselves. The participants’ eye movements were recorded while they performed the tasks. Behavioral results revealed that, compared with the D-single task, participants selected more choices correctly predicted by EV and EU theories, and took a longer time to make a decision in the D-veryone and D-multiple tasks. Furthermore, eye movement measurements revealed the following. (1) The scanpath patterns of the D-everyone task and D-multiple task were similar but different from those of the D-single task. (2) The depth of information acquisition and the level of complexity of information processing in the D-everyone task and D-multiple task was higher than that in the D-single task. (3) The direction of information search in the D-everyone task and D-multiple task was more alternative-based than that in the D-single task. (4) The eye-tracking measures mediated the relationship between the task and the EV-consistent choice. In summary, behavioral and eye movement results supported our hypotheses that participants were likely to follow an expectation strategy in the D-everyone and D-multiple tasks, whereas they were likely to follow a heuristic/nonexpectation strategy in the D-single task. We found that expectation-maximization-based theories could capture the choice of an individual when making decisions for everyone and for self in a multiple-play condition but could not capture the choice of an individual when making decisions for self in a single-play condition. The evidence for the discrepancy between everyone and every one, which was first reported in our study, implied that the possible reason why expectation-maximization-based theories do not work is that a default compatibility between the full set (everyone) and the subset (every one) does not exist. Our findings contribute to an improved understanding of the boundaries of expectation-maximization-based theories and those of heuristic/non-expectation models. Our findings may also shed light on the general issue of the classification of risky decision-making theories.

关键词风险决策 为所有人决策 期望值最大化 为自己–为所有人决策差异 眼动追踪技术
2022
语种中文
DOI10.3724/SP.J.1041.2022.01517
发表期刊心理学报
ISSN0439-755X
卷号54期号:12页码:1517-1531
项目简介

国家自然科学基金项目(71901126);; 国家社会科学基金重大项目(19ZDA358);; 教育部人文社会科学研究青年项目(19YJC190013);; 中央高校基本科研业务费专项资金(63222045)资助

引用统计
被引频次:3[WOS]   [WOS记录]     [WOS相关记录]
文献类型期刊论文
条目标识符http://ir.psych.ac.cn/handle/311026/43686
专题中国科学院行为科学重点实验室
作者单位1.南开大学周恩来政府管理学院社会心理学系
2.中国科学院行为科学重点实验室中国科学院心理研究所
3.中国科学院大学
4.浙江大学心理与行为科学系
推荐引用方式
GB/T 7714
刘洪志,李兴珊,李纾,等. 基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策中为自己–为所有人决策差异的眼动研究[J]. 心理学报,2022,54(12):1517-1531.
APA 刘洪志,李兴珊,李纾,&饶俪琳.(2022).基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策中为自己–为所有人决策差异的眼动研究.心理学报,54(12),1517-1531.
MLA 刘洪志,et al."基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策中为自己–为所有人决策差异的眼动研究".心理学报 54.12(2022):1517-1531.
条目包含的文件
文件名称/大小 文献类型 版本类型 开放类型 使用许可
基于期望值最大化的理论何时失效:风险决策(818KB)期刊论文出版稿限制开放CC BY-NC-SA请求全文
个性服务
推荐该条目
保存到收藏夹
查看访问统计
导出为Endnote文件
谷歌学术
谷歌学术中相似的文章
[刘洪志]的文章
[李兴珊]的文章
[李纾]的文章
百度学术
百度学术中相似的文章
[刘洪志]的文章
[李兴珊]的文章
[李纾]的文章
必应学术
必应学术中相似的文章
[刘洪志]的文章
[李兴珊]的文章
[李纾]的文章
相关权益政策
暂无数据
收藏/分享
所有评论 (0)
暂无评论
 

除非特别说明,本系统中所有内容都受版权保护,并保留所有权利。